What are the characteristics of an efficient firm in developing countries’ private sector? The case of Vietnam

 

Linh PHAM1

1 University of Central Oklahoma, United State

 

Abstract. The private sector is the primary source of local development in developing countries. Previous research in developing countries has documented many factors contributing to firm-level efficiency. However, which of these factors are most likely to correlate with efficiency? This paper studies the relative importance of the firm-level efficiency determinants in a transitional economy, using a firm-level panel dataset in Vietnam between 2005 and 2015. The empirical results show that firm-specific production and labor characteristics are the most significant determinants of efficiency. Thus, firms actively seeking to improve their own production process and labor force can be well-rewarded. Moreover, government technical supports and human resource training programs, combined with anti-corruption efforts, are beneficial for firm-level efficiency, thereby improving the living standards in developing economies. 

Keywords: efficiency, SMEs, transitional economy

JEL Codes: D2, L2, O25

How to cite: PHAM, L. (2018). What are the characteristics of an efficient firm in developing countries’ private sector? The case of Vietnam. Journal of Economic Development, Environment and People, 7(2), 39-59. doi:http://dx.doi.org/10.26458/jedep.v7i2.584

1.       Introduction

Private enterprises are the main contributor to local development in developing countries [1]. Previous research on firms’ performance in developing countries have identified many factors that contribute to firm-level efficiency [6, 7, 8]. Yet, due to limited availability of data, little is known about the relative importance of these efficiency determinants. For this reason, many efforts have been made to improve the quality of the firm-level data in developing countries. In light of the recent improvements in firm-level data for developing countries, this paper presents a comprehensive analysis on the contribution of various internal and external factors to the profitability of private enterprises in developing countries.

Specifically, I ask the following research questions. First, how efficient are firms in developing countries? Second, what are the most important characteristics of an efficient firm? Finally, what policy is the most effective at improving the firm-level efficiency? I answer these questions by combining the stochastic frontier framework, an econometric technique commonly used in the study of productive efficiency, with a detailed firm-level panel dataset of Vietnamese firms between 2005 and 2015.

Vietnam is an interesting site to study the above research questions. First, as a transitional economy, Vietnam shared many similarities to other developing countries. For example, small and medium firms comprise most of the Vietnamese private sector and hire the largest share of the Vietnamese labor force [5]. Moreover, like other transitional economies, Vietnam has undergone several reforms, which transformed the country from a closed economy to an open market economy.  Second, since 2005, the Vietnam Central Institute for Economic Management (CIEM) has established the Small and Medium Enterprise survey to improve the understanding of firms’ performance in Vietnam [2]. This comprehensive survey covers multiple industries and geographical regions and includes both formally-registered and informal firms. The detailed information provided by this dataset is useful to analyze the relative importance of various determinants of firm-level profitability in a transitional economy.

To study the relative importance of the firm-level efficiency determinants, I employ a stochastic profit frontier framework, a technique commonly used in the study of productive efficiency [9]. Under this framework, firms maximize profits by choosing a combination of inputs and outputs, taking as given technology and prices. Compared to the regular linear regression model, this profit frontier model has two advantages. First, it allows the estimation of the gap between firms’ actual profit and their maximum attainable profit. Second, the stochastic frontier model allows the separation of firms’ deviations from the optimal profit into two categories, in contrast to regular linear regression models which lump all deviations from a firm’s optimal profit level into one symmetrically distributed random error term. The first type of deviation is due to randomness in the production process such as weather or other acts of nature, therefore, it either positively or negatively influences firm’s profitability and is modelled using the symmetrically distributed error term, as in traditional linear regression models. The second type of deviation comes from the firms’ inability to allocate their resources efficiently, given technology, prices and the existence of random events. This resource allocation failure negatively impacts the firm’s profitability; therefore, it is modelled as a one-sided error that only takes negative values. The direct modelling of this resource allocation failure is a useful tool to study the relative importance between the main determinants of firm-level efficiency.

The estimation results show that on average, private manufacturing firms in Vietnam lose about 29.9% of annual profit due to inefficiency, where the problem of inefficiency is more severe in heavy industries than light industries. Moreover, I find that firm’s size is the most significant internal characteristic of an efficient firm, followed by innovation and human capital. Thus, policies that encourage firms to improve their own internal strength, such as improved access to the labor market, innovation incentives and labor training programs, can promote the firm-level efficiency. Other external characteristics such as competition and exporting activity also matter for the firms’ efficiency, where firms who face competition or engage in exporting activity are more profitable. In addition, better access to credit and lower bribery also increases the firm-level efficiency. The results imply the importance of creating a healthy competitive business environment and improving the transparency of the legal system in the growth of small and medium firms.

This paper is related to the extensive literature studying firm-level productivity growth. This literature has identified a long list of factors that influence the firm-level productivity, however, little has been known about the relative importance of these factors, due to the lack of a comprehensive firm-level dataset in developing countries [13]. Therefore, while previous studies gain useful insights into the role of individual factors in determining productivity growth, they also present a challenge for policymakers to identify the most important policy targets. Using a detailed firm-level panel dataset in Vietnam, this paper provides practical policy recommendations to increase productivity growth in developing countries through ranking various efficiency determinants by their orders of effectiveness. As the firm-level productivity is known to be an important indicator of aggregate industry- or country-level productivity [1], this paper also contributes to the literature studying the sources of aggregate productivity growth by identifying the most important productivity drivers at the micro level.

The rest of the paper is organized as follow. Section 2 presents the econometric framework while section 3 describes the empirical context of the study. Section 4 discusses the main estimation results and section 5 presents the robustness analysis. Finally, a concluding remark is provided in section 6.

1.       Econometric framework

The goal of this study is to understand the relative importance of various factors in determining productive efficiency in developing countries. The literature studying productive efficiency is extensive and can be dated back to the theoretical work by [4], who defines firms’ efficiency as the distance between firms’ current productive status and their maximum attainable outcome based on criteria such as production output, cost or profit. Econometric specification of firms’ production behavior that allows for the existence of inefficiency is known as stochastic frontier analysis. This technique assumes that firms operate on or beneath a productive frontier, which captures the optimal allocations of production activities such that firms’ production cost (profit) is minimized (maximized). Firms who operate on the productive frontier are considered efficient while firms who operate underneath the productive frontier are considered inefficient. The further a firm is from its productive frontier, the more inefficient it is.

Stochastic frontier analysis assumes two factors that affect firms’ deviations from their productive frontier. The first characterizes the randomness in the production process (for example, weather or other acts of nature) and thus takes on both positive and negative values. The second characterizes the possibility that the firm is operating inefficiently and thus takes on only negative values. Thus, econometric specification under stochastic frontier analysis departs from the assumption of a symmetric random error in traditional ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions. Instead, it involves both a two-sided error term that captures the randomness in production and a one-sided error term that captures firms’ inefficiency. This allows the estimation of the mean and variance of efficiency, thereby informing policymakers about the extent to which efficiency vary among firms [9].

Many previous studies rely on the estimation of production or cost frontiers to determine the efficiency level of a decision-making unit. Under this approach, firms choose between different combinations of inputs to produce an exogenous level of output. While the assumption of exogenous output is appropriate in some settings, in most cases, producers are responsible for choosing both the input and output quantities. To account for this, the estimation of firms’ efficiency measurement should involve a profit frontier specification. In this paper, I employ the stochastic profit frontier framework to estimate the profit efficiency of Vietnamese SMEs and to analyze the factors that contribute to the performance of these firms. Following (Kumbakar 2015), the specification of the stochastic profit frontier model is as follow:

 

(1)

where  denotes firm and  denotes time.  denotes a firm’s actual short-run profit, which is calculated as its revenue minus its variable costs (the sum of labor and material costs).  represents the firm’s short-run profit frontier, which is the maximum attainable profit the firm could achieve, given the variable input price vector (), the output price () and the quantity of fixed input (). This econometric framework assumes that firms are price-takers, which is a reasonable assumption for small and medium firms.

Two factors contribute to the deviation of firm’s actual profit from its profit frontier. First, there exists randomness in the production process, due to an unusually favorable (or unfavorable) operating environment (for example, weather or other acts of nature), which may cause firms to perform better (or worse) than their potential. This randomness in the production process is captured in the mean-zero error term . Second, a firm can deviate from its profit frontier because it was operating inefficiently, where its chosen production plan does not lead to the maximum attainable profit. These mistakes in the production of outputs and uses of inputs are captured in the non-negative random inefficiency parameter . Finally, , , and  capture industry-, time- and industrytime fixed effects. The fixed effects capture the variations between industries and over time of the profit frontier.

Estimating the model in (1) requires parametric specifications of the functional form of  as well as the distributions of  and . I assume that the profit frontier  takes the form of a translog profit function. This profit function must satisfy homogeneity of degree one in input and output prices. This can be achieved by normalizing the input prices and profit by the output price. Let , the normalized translog profit frontier () is as follow:

 


(2)

, where  denotes the price of variable input  for firm  during period  and  is equal to  (raw materials) or  (labor).

Combining (1) and (2) yields the following estimation equation:

 

(3)

In addition to the homogeneity restriction, the above profit function also satisfies a symmetry condition, namely  and  . Finally,  follows a normal distribution () and  follows a truncated normal distribution ().

The objective of this paper is not only to estimate the level of efficiency for Vietnamese SMEs but also to identify the factors that contribute to inefficiency. To do so, I model the distribution function of the inefficiency parameter  as a function of other explanatory variables. Specifically:

 

(4)

 

where  is a firm-specific vector of variables which may influence the efficiency of a firm and  is the corresponding coefficient vectors. The efficiency explanatory vector  includes firm-specific characteristics that determine a firm’s success or failure at allocating their resources in a profit-maximizing manner. Since  captures the amount of profit lost due to inefficiency, a positive  indicates a positive relationship between the efficiency explanatory variable  and a firm’s inefficiency level, thereby suggesting a negative relationship between  and afirm’s profitability. On the other hand, a negative  suggests a positive relationship between  and a firm’s profitability.

Equations (3) and (4) are simultaneously estimated using a maximum likelihood estimator. Based on the estimation results, the profit efficiency can be defined as:

 

(5)

 

where  measures the actual profit for firm  at time  relative to the profit of a fully efficient firm who is subject to the same prices and fixed input quantity.

Finally, following [9], the implied changes in expected profit from changes in the efficiency explanatory variables () are derived from the estimated values of  and . Specifically, the marginal effect of the th element of  is given by:

 

(6)

 

where  denotes the th element of  and  is the corresponding coefficient estimated from equation (4).  and  are the probability density and probability distribution functions of a standard normal variable. The magnitudes of the estimated marginal effects in equation (6) allows us to quantify the relative importance of various factors on the firm-level efficiency.

2.       Data

To understand the role of different variables on firm-level efficiency in developing countries, I analyze the stochastic profit frontier model in the context of Vietnam. As a transitional economy, Vietnam shares several similarities with other developing countries. First, the private sector, which consists primarily of small and medium enterprises (SMEs), is crucial to economic development [5]. Second, like other transitional economies, Vietnam has undergone several reforms for the last three decades, which transforms the country from a closed, centrally-planned economy to an open, market-oriented economy.

The common characteristics between Vietnam and other developing countries make Vietnam a good case study of the business environment in developing countries. Additionally, since 2005, the Vietnam Center Institute for Economic Management (CIEM) has established the Small and Medium Enterprise (SME) survey to better understand the operation of SMEs [2]. This comprehensive dataset covers different types of ownership, industries and geographical regions of Vietnam and contains rich firm-level information, such as their financial accounts, production and sales structure, employment and cost structure, economic constraints and potentials. Therefore, taking advantage of the rich Vietnam SME dataset, this paper aims at ranking the contributions of various factors to the firm-level productivity.  Table 1 shows the distribution of firms across types of ownership and industry.

I employ the stochastic profit frontier approach discussed in section 2 as the main empirical framework. The econometric specification of a firm’s stochastic profit frontier consists of two components: (i) the profit frontier component that describes firms’ optimal level of profits given their input and output prices (equation (3)); and (ii) a component that models the sources of inefficiency for each firm (equation (4)). Therefore, it requires two sets of variables. First, estimating the profit frontier in equation (3) requires information on firm-level annual profits, fixed inputs, and firm-level prices of output and variable inputs. Second, estimating the efficiency explanatory equation (4) and the marginal effects of different variables on efficiency (equation (6)) requires data on the internal and external factors that potentially contribute to the discrepancy between firms’ current profit and their optimal profit level. Next, I describe in detail the variables needed to estimate this profit frontier model.

Table 1. Distribution of firms across ownership types and industries.

 

 

Ownership type

 

Survey
year

Industry

Household

Sole
proprietorship

Partnership/
Collective/
Cooperative

Limited
liability

Joint
stock

Total

2005

Heavy

878

171

65

246

29

1,389

Light

1,012

109

31

183

25

1,360

Total

1,890

280

96

429

54

2,749

2007

Heavy

602

86

53

177

22

940

Light

1,155

111

49

261

32

1,608

Total

1,757

197

102

438

54

2,548

2009

Heavy

535

83

40

217

40

915

Light

1,170

121

34

290

50

1,665

Total

1,705

204

74

507

90

2,580

2011

Heavy

482

86

41

231

42

882

Light

1,143

116

27

287

59

1,632

Total

1,625

202

68

518

101

2,514

2013

Heavy

453

89

29

244

55

870

Light

1,141

113

26

307

59

1,646

Total

1,594

202

55

551

114

2,516

2015

Heavy

555

80

31

305

65

1,036

Light

1,088

82

22

313

58

1,563

Total

1,643

162

53

618

123

2,599

Light industries include firms producing food, beverages and tobacco products; textile and leather-related products; paper and printing products; and furniture manufacture. Heavy-industries include manufacturers of machinery and equipment, chemical, metal, rubber and non-metallic products.

 

2.1.          Profit frontier variables

The analysis of the profit frontier equation (3) requires the construction of firm-level profit (), output price (), variable input prices (), and fixed input (), where variable inputs consist of labor () and raw materials ().

Profit () is measured by the annual gross margin, which is the difference between a firm’s revenue from production and its variable costs. Fixed inputs () is measured by the value of all productive physical assets, which includes the values of buildings, machinery and equipment. The price of labor () is calculated by dividing the total wage expenditure by the number of employees (i.e. the quantity of labor).

While firm-level data on gross margin (), capital stock (), labor, total revenue and total input expenditure are available, firm-level data are not available on the price of raw materials and output. One approach to generate input and output prices is to use the industry-level price indices (e.g. [12]). To account for the price variations among firms, each price used in this study is weighed by the transactions made during the year through different market channels. Specifically, the price of output () and raw materials () are proxied by:

 

(7)

 

(8)

where ,  denotes firm and time.  () is the share of output (raw materials) that is sold (acquired) domestically, while  () is the share of output (raw materials) that is sold (acquired) internationally through exports (imports).  represents the price index of domestic goods while  is the price index of exported goods. Finally,  is the price index of domestic raw materials and  is the price index of imported raw materials. Data for the price indices are extracted from the Statistical Yearbook of Vietnam Statistical Yearbook of Vietnam [5]. The construction of the prices in equation (7) is based on two assumptions. First, firms are price takers in the output and input markets. And second, firms produce a single output and use only one type of raw material in production. In this case, the price-taking assumption is reasonable because small and medium firms in the dataset often operate industries with a large number of firms such as the food, tobacco and beverage industry or the textile industry, therefore, given their smaller sizes, these firms have little power over the market prices.

Table 2. Summary statistics of profit frontier variables by industry and by ownership status


 

Profit

Raw material expenditure

Wage expenditure

Physical capital 

By industry:

Light industries

601.56 (4132.78)

3910.26 (88854.18)

469.36 (1852.43)

3403.83 (14246.52) 

Heavy industries

871.03 (6395.50)

5677.73 (70372.75)

529.81 (1516.75)

4852.99 (20638.28) 

By ownership status:

Household firms

152.66 (393.80)

 600.51 (2216.56)

102.72 (179.75)

1286.42 (3110.27) 

Non-household firms

1805.7 (8950.7)

12132.91 (135281.7)

1156.33 (2623.96)

9163.98 (27987.82) 

All numbers are in millions of Vietnam dongs.

Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations.

 

Moreover, most firms in the dataset produce only one type of output and the average number of products that each firm produces is 1.16, therefore, without loss of generality, we can assume a single output price for every firm. On the other hand, raw materials typically include many different items. However, it is common in the literature to treat materials as a homogeneous input [10]. Table 2 reports the average profit, raw material expenditure, wage expenditure and value of the capital stock for all SMEs over the period of 2005-2015.

2.2.          Efficiency explanatory variables

The profit frontier variables discussed above are helpful in estimating firms’ maximum attainable profit, given the quantity of fixed inputs and the prices of output and variable inputs. The gap between this maximum profit and the actual profit allows us to infer about the level of profit efficiency for each firm. Possible factors that might affect this efficiency gap are modeled using the efficiency explanatory equation (4). These factors are either inherent within the firms themselves (the internal environment) or capture characteristics of the business and legal environment in which the firms operate (the external environment). Both the internal and external factors are available at the firm level and are discussed in detail below.

3.2.1. The internal determinants of profit efficiency

Internal factors such as human capital, firm’s age, size and improvements of the production process have been known in the literature as important determinants of firm’s performance (for example, [8, 11]). In this paper, human capital is proxied by both the characteristics of the firms’ owner-managers and labor training activity. A firm’s effort to upgrade its production process is captured by a dummy variable which equal 1 if the firm introduces a new product, modifies its existing product, or modify its production process in the previous year. Firm’s age is measured as the number of years since the firm’s establishment up until the survey year while firm’s size is measured using the number of employees.

3.2.2. The external determinants of profit efficiency

Besides the internal characteristics of the businesses, external environmental factors also play a role in determining firm-level performance. These external factors represent the business and legal environment in which the firms operate.

First, the business environment is captured by dummy variables which show the various relationships between the firms and other business entities. Competition is measured by a dummy variable which equals 1 if the firm reports that they faced competition. A firm’s exporting activity is measured by a dummy variable that equals 1 if the firm exports, while a firm’s subcontracting activity is measured by a dummy variable that equals 1 if the firm is a subcontractor. Besides competition and business partnership, the ability to obtain capital also determines firm-level success [7]. In this paper, a firm’s access to formal credit is measured by a dummy variable which equals 1 if the firm has difficulty in obtaining formal credit while a firm’s use of informal credit is measured by a dummy variable which equals 1 if the firm use informal credit as a source of financing. Finally, to capture other characteristics of the business environment, dummy variables which indicate a firm’s locations are also included in the analysis.

Besides the business environment, the legal systems can also influence a firm’s performance [3, 15]. In this paper, I consider three main indicators of the legal environment, which are formalization, government assistance and corruption. Formalization is measured by a dummy variable which equals 1 if the firm is formally registered while government assistance is captured by a dummy variable which equals 1 if the firm receives assistance from the government. Finally, corruption is measured by the amount of bribery that firms pay as a percentage of total revenue. Table 3 provides the description of the efficiency explanatory variables included in this study and table 4 provide the summary statistics of these variables.

Table 3. Summary of efficiency explanatory variables

Variable

Description

Internal environment:

Owner’s education

=1 if owner finishes primary school

Labor training

=1 if the firm has provided training for its labor force since the last survey

Innovation

=1 if the firm introduces a new product, modifies its existing product, or modify its production process in the last survey.

Firm’s age

=Survey year - Year of establishment.

Firm’s size

Log of the number of workers.

Business environment:

Competition

=1 if the firm faces competition.

Subcontracting

=1 if the firm is a subcontractor.

Exporting

=1 if the firm exports.

Formal credit constraint

=1 if the firm has had any difficulty in obtaining formal credit since last survey.

Informal credit usage

=1 if the firm has used informal credit since last survey.

Industrial zone

=1 if the firm is located inside an industrial zone.

Urban

=1 if the firm is located in an urban area.

Legal environment:

Formalization

=1 if the firm is formally registered.

Assistance

=1 if the firm has received any government assistance since last survey.

Bribery

Amount of bribery (% of revenue).

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Table 4. Summary statistics of efficiency explanatory variables

All firms

By industry

By ownership status

 

Light

Heavy

Household

Non-household

 

Internal environment:

Owner’s education

0.976 (0.153)

0.975 (0.156)

0.978 (0.148)

0.967 (0.179)

0.994 (0.080)

 

Labor training

0.162 (0.369)

0.138 (0.345)

0.192 (0.394)

0.086 (0.281)

0.309 (0.462)

 

Innovation

0.424 (0.494)

0.361 (0.480)

0.500 (0.500)

0.365 (0.482)

0.535 (0.499)

 

Firm’s age

14.276 (10.362)

15.080 (10.749)

13.286 (9.775)

15.873 (10.679)

11.211 (8.960)

 

Firm’s size

1.844 (1.169)

1.717 (1.176)

1.999 (1.141)

1.296 (0.774)

2.895 (1.076)

 

Business environment:

Competition

0.876 (0.329)

0.858 (0.349)

0.899 (0.301)

0.847 (0.360)

0.933 (0.251)

 

Subcontracting

0.103 (0.305)

0.085 (0.279)

0.126 (0.332)

0.086 (0.281)

0.137 (0.344)

 

Exporting

0.062 (0.242)

0.074 (0.261)

0.049 (0.215)

0.013 (0.112)

0.158 (0.365)

 

Formal credit constraint

0.236 (0.424)

0.209 (0.406)

0.269 (0.443)

0.209 (0.407)

0.287 (0.452)

 

Informal credit usage

0.540 (0.498)

0.513 (0.500)

0.574 (0.495)

0.494 (0.500)

0.629 (0.483)

 

Industrial zone

0.054 (0.225)

0.044 (0.204)

0.066 (0.248)

0.015 (0.122)

0.127 (0.333)

 

Urban

0.437 (0.496)

0.386 (0.487)

0.500 (0.500)

0.318 (0.466)

0.665 (0.472)

 

Legal environment:

Formalization

0.714 (0.452)

0.669 (0.471)

0.771 (0.420)

0.573 (0.495)

0.987 (0.114)

 

Assistance

0.227 (0.419)

0.219 (0.413)

0.238 (0.426)

0.209 (0.407)

0.262 (0.440)

 

Bribery

0.001 (0.011)

0.001 (0.007)

0.002 (0.014)

0.001 (0.011)

0.002 (0.010)

 

Observations

14,975

8,262

6,713

9,854

5,121

 

Numbers in parentheses are standard deviations.

 

3.       Main empirical results

This section presents the main estimation results. Table 5 reports the estimation results of the profit frontier equation (3), the efficiency explanatory equation (4) and the marginal effects on expected profit of each efficiency explanatory variable () for the full sample (columns(1)-(3)), the light industries (columns (4)-(6)) and the heavy industries (columns (7)-(9)) between 2005 and 2015. Light industries include manufacturers of products such as food, beverages and tobacco products; textile and leather-related products; paper and printing products; and furniture manufacture. Heavy-industry firms include manufacturers of machinery and equipment, chemical, metal, rubber and non-metallic products.

3.1.          How efficient are private firms in Vietnam?

The estimation results for the whole sample in table 5 show that the average profit efficiency of non-state manufacturing firms between 2005 and 2015 is 70.1%. In other words, on average, firms earn 29.9% less than their estimated maximum attainable profit due to inefficiency. To get a sense of the potential loss in profit, I compare this to the average profit of a firm in this dataset. The average reported annual profit for a firm in the dataset is 715.6 million Vietnam dongs (approximately 31,000 USD). An average efficiency level of 70.1% implies that firms could increase their annual profit by about 305.2 million Vietnam dongs (approximately 13,000 USD) if they perform at their best potentials. The industry-specific estimation results indicate that on average, firms in the light industries are slightly more efficient than firms in the heavy industries. The average profit efficiency is 70.8% for light-industry firms and 68.0% for heavy industry firms. The average reported profit for firms in the light industries is 601.5 million Vietnam dongs (approximately 26,135 USD), which implies that light-industry firms could increase their profit by 248 million Vietnam dongs (approximately 10,775 USD) if they operate efficiently. Similarly, the average reported profit for firms in the heavy industries is 855.5 million Vietnam dongs (approximately 31,170 USD) and a profit efficiency level of 68.0% implies that the average loss due to inefficiency of heavy-industry firms in the dataset is 402.6 million Vietnam dongs (approximately 17,500 USD).

In short, the results show that firms are not operating at their full potential. This finding is consistent with previous studies in other countries (e.g. [6, 14]). Next, I will analyze the relative importance of various internal and external characteristics on the firm-level efficiency.

3.2.          What internal and external characteristics do an efficient firm possess?

The profit frontier model in section 2 not only reveals about the distance between a firm’s current level profit and its maximum attainable profit, but also allows the identification of the determinants of efficiency. The bottom half of table 5 presents the estimation results of the efficiency explanatory equation (4) and the implied change or marginal effect of each variable that explains efficiency on expected profit. Overall, the profit efficiency level of a firm depends on characteristics of its internal environment, regardless of which industry it is in, therefore, a firm’s action to improve its internal environment can be beneficial for its efficiency.

The estimation results in table 5 show that the three most important internal characteristics of an efficient firm are its size, its effort to upgrade the production process or to improve its products, with firms’ size being the most significant contributor to the firm-level profitability. These results are consistent when the whole sample is divided into light-industry firms and heavy-industry firms (columns (4)-(9) of table 5). One explanation is that while the benefits from expanding a firm’s size can be realized in the short run, the impact lag of other variables on efficiency is longer. For example, it takes more time for a new production process to be fully efficient and for new products to be accepted by consumers. Similarly, it takes more time for human capital improvements to be translated into higher profitability.

 

 

Table 5. The profit frontier and determinants of profit efficiency between 2005 and 2015

 

Whole sample

Light industries

Heavy industries

 

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

 

Coef.

Std.Err.

Coef.

Std.Err.

Coef.

Std.Err.

Profit frontier equation:

 

1.761**

(0.887)

 

2.448**

(1.192)

 

-0.806

(1.385)

 

 

-0.075

(0.074)

 

-0.401***

(0.098)

 

0.407***

(0.123)

 

 

0.106***

(0.031)

 

0.209***

(0.039)

 

-0.125**

(0.053)

 

 

1.850***

(0.380)

 

1.456***

(0.457)

 

1.768**

(0.817)

 

 

0.032***

(0.009)

 

0.017

(0.012)

 

0.031*

(0.016)

 

 

0.034***

(0.002)

 

0.031***

(0.002)

 

0.043***

(0.003)

 

 

0.509***

(0.169)

 

0.687***

(0.227)

 

0.227

(0.266)

 

 

-0.091

(0.089)

 

-0.181

(0.121)

 

0.206

(0.134)

 

 

0.085***

(0.007)

 

0.119***

(0.010)

 

0.025**

(0.012)

 

Constant

-0.837***

(0.147)

 

-1.569***

(0.184)

 

0.570**

(0.258)

 

Average profit efficiency

70.1%

 

 

70.8%

 

 

68.0%

 

Efficiency explanatory equation:

Internal environment:

Owner’s education

-0.291**

(0.145)

0.065

-0.219

(0.184)

0.05

-0.432*

(0.239)

0.105

Labor training

-0.205

(0.136)

0.046

-0.601**

(0.246)

0.138

0.025

(0.152)

-0.006

New product

-0.061

(0.111)

0.014

-0.082

(0.159)

0.019

-0.148

(0.146)

0.036

Product modification

-0.428***

(0.077)

0.096

-0.455***

(0.114)

0.104

-0.259**

(0.108)

0.063

Process upgrading

-0.470***

(0.145)

0.106

-0.667***

(0.223)

0.153

-0.119

(0.176)

0.029

Firm’s age

0.013***

(0.002)

-0.003

0.013***

(0.003)

-0.003

0.012***

(0.004)

-0.003

Firm’s size

-1.464***

(0.056)

0.329

-1.473***

(0.078)

0.337

-1.359***

(0.080)

0.331

Business environment:

Competition

-0.160**

(0.069)

0.036

-0.152*

(0.085)

0.035

-0.207*

(0.125)

0.05

Subcontracting

0.231**

(0.102)

-0.052

0.216

(0.165)

-0.049

0.134

(0.130)

-0.033

Exporting

-1.130**

(0.498)

0.254

-1.749**

(0.883)

0.4

-0.909*

(0.550)

0.221

Formal credit constraint

-0.094

(0.073)

0.021

-0.172*

(0.100)

0.039

-0.006

(0.108)

0.001

Informal credit usage

-0.154**

(0.061)

0.035

-0.159**

(0.079)

0.036

-0.171*

(0.099)

0.042

Industrial zone

-0.560*

(0.293)

0.126

-0.443

(0.385)

0.101

-0.712

(0.463)

0.174

Urban

-0.096

(0.175)

0.021

-0.127

(0.257)

0.029

0.072

(0.233)

-0.018

Legal environment:

Formalization

-0.085

(0.077)

0.019

-0.031

(0.104)

0.007

-0.208*

(0.122)

0.051

Government assistance

-0.086

(0.076)

0.019

-0.044

(0.100)

0.01

-0.071

(0.118)

0.017

Bribery

4.506

(2.898)

-1.011

12.969**

(5.111)

-2.969

12.389*

(7.133)

-3.018

Constant

1.290***

(0.262)

 

1.248***

(0.330)

 

2.226***

(0.400)

 

 

Log likelihood

-18801.88

 

 

-10284.75

 

 

-7233.26

 

Observations

14,484

 

 

8,011

 

 

5,512

 

Sub-industry FE

YES

 

 

YES

 

 

YES

 

Year FE

YES

 

 

YES

 

 

YES

 

Standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 

 

In addition to the firm-specific characteristics, the external environment in which the firms operate also plays a role in shaping their efficiency. The results show that competition, exporting and access to credit are the largest contributors to efficiency of firms in both heavy and light industries. Specifically, competition increases firm-level efficiency, as it motivates firms to improve its production and encourages inefficient firms to exit the market. Table 5 also suggests that firms who engage in exporting activities and have better access to credit tend to be more efficient. Finally, bribery is associated with lower level of profitability in both the light and heavy industries.

4.       Robustness checks

This section presents some robustness check of the main estimation results in section 4. Specifically, I consider alternative sub-samples in the dataset and alternative specifications of the profit frontier models.

To account for the fact the different types of firms have access to different technology, I apply the stochastic profit frontier model in section 2 to various subsamples in the dataset. Specifically, I re-estimate the profit frontier model using only incumbent firms who are present in all six rounds of the survey between 2005 and 2015. This is to account for the potential bias from the inclusion of firms who are not present in all rounds of the survey. In addition, I further classify firms into household (family-owned) businesses and non-household businesses. Table 6 presents a summary of the estimation results of the above robustness checks for the whole sample (columns (1)-(4)), the light industries (columns (5)-(8)) and the heavy industries (columns (9)-(12)). Overall, the main estimation results still hold for these alternative sub-samples. However, household firms are more likely to benefit from formalization while non-household firms are more prone to bribery. This reflects that on average, non-household businesses pay bribery more frequently than household businesses. Thus, this also suggests the existence of a crowding-out effect between formalization and corruption.

Next, I estimate the profit efficiency for all firms in the sample under alternative specifications of the model described in section 2. This is to account for the potential correlations between closely related variables. Table 7 shows the marginal effects of each efficiency explanatory variable on the profit efficiency of the full sample, under alternative measures of human capital (columns (2)-(3)), production upgrading activities (columns (4)-(6)), access to credit (columns (7)-(8)) and firm’s location (columns (9)-(10)). Overall, the main results in section 4 still hold under these alternative specifications.

Table 6. Marginal effects on profit efficiency (), alternative sub-samples

 

Whole sample

Light industries

Heavy industries

 

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

 

All firms

Incumbent firms only

Household firms only

Non-household firms only

All firms

Incumbent firms only

Household firms only

Non-household firms only

All firms

Incumbent firms only

Household firms only

Non-household firms only

Internal environment

Owner’s education

+**

+*

+**

+

+

+

+

+

+*

+

+**

+

Labor training

+

+

+***

+

+**

+

+***

+

-

+

+

-

New product introduction

+

+

-

+

+

-

-

+

+

+

+

-

Product modification

+***

+

+***

-

+****

+

+***

-

+**

+

+***

+

New process introduction

+***

+

+**

+**

+***

+

+***

+*

+

+

-

+

Firm’s age

-***

-**

-***

-***

-***

-**

-***

-**

-***

-

-**

-**

Firm’s size

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

 

Business environment

Competition

+**

+***

+***

+

+*

+**

+*

-

+*

+

+

+

Subcontracting

-**

+

-**

-

-

+

-*

-

-

+

-

+

Exporting

+**

+

+

+**

+**

+

+

+

+*

+

-

+**

Formal credit constraint

+

-

+

-

+*

-

+

+

+

+

+

-

Informal credit usage

+**

+*

+**

-

+*

+*

+**

-

+*

+

+

+

Industrial zone

+*

+

+

-

+

+

+

-

+

+

+

+

Urban

+

-

+***

+***

+

-

+**

+

-

-

+

+***

 

Legal environment

Formalization

+

+

+***

-

+

+

+**

+

+*

+

+**

-

Government assistance

+

+

+

-

+

-

+

-

+

+

+***

-

Bribery

-

-*

-

-***

-**

-

-

-*

-*

-*

-

-***

 

Observations

14484

4727

9644

4840

8011

2701

5722

2289

5512

1903

3244

2268 

Industry FE

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES 

Year FE

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

The table summarizes the marginal effects of each efficiency explanatory variable on the profit efficiency () of various types of Vietnamese SMEs between 2005 and 2015. 

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 

 

Table 7. Marginal effects on profit efficiency (), alternative specifications of the profit frontier model

 

Baseline

Alternative human capital measures

Alternative production upgrading measures

Alternative credit access measures

Alternative location measures

Interactive variables

 

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

Internal environment

Owner’s education

+**

+***

 

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+** 

Labor training

+

 

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

-*

New product

+

+

+

+*

 

 

+

+

+

+

+

+

Product modification

+***

+***

+***

 

+***

 

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

Process upgrading

+***

+***

+***

 

 

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

Firm’s age

-***

-***

-***

-***

-***

-***

-***

-***

-***

-***

-

-***

Firm’s size

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

+***

Firm’s age*Size

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

-***

 

Labor training*Size

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

+***

 

Business environment

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Competition

+**

+**

+**

+***

+***

+***

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

Subcontracting

-**

-**

-**

-*

-**

-*

-**

-**

-**

-**

-**

-**

Exporting

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

+**

Formal credit constraint

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

Informal credit usage

+**

+***

+**

+***

+**

+**

 

+***

+**

+**

+**

+**

Industrial zone

+*

+*

+*

+*

+

+*

+*

+*

+*

 

+*

+*

Urban

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

 

+

+

+

 

Legal environment

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Formalization

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

Other support

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

+

Bribery

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

 

Observations

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484

14484 

Industry FE

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

Year FE

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

YES

The table summarizes the marginal effects of each efficiency explanatory variable on the profit efficiency () for the full sample of Vietnamese SMEs between 2005 and 2015 under various specifications of the profit frontier model. 

The baseline column (1) summarizes the marginal effects reported in column (3) of table 5. 

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 

 

To capture the interaction between different variables, I also incorporate interactive variables into the analysis. Columns (11) and (12) of table 7 summarize the marginal effects of the efficiency explanatory variables with interactive variables between firm’s age and size (column (11)) and between labor training and firm’s size (column (12)). The marginal effects of the interaction variable between firm’s age and size is negative and statistically significant (column (11)). This suggests that, while larger firms are more efficient, the marginal effect of expanding a firm’s size on profit efficiency declines as the firm ages. This is in line with the fact that older firms are more likely to use older technology than their younger counterparts. Column (12) of table 7 explores the interaction between a firm’s size and whether the firm provides training to their workers. The marginal effects of firm’s size and the labor training*size interaction variable are positive and statistically significant, which implies that larger firms with labor training programs are more efficient than other firms.

One assumption of the profit efficiency model is that firms are pricetakers. Firms who do not face competition are often price setters, therefore the inclusion of those firms may bias the results. To this end, I re-estimate the profit frontier model, excluding firms not facing competition from the sample. Under this specification, the main conclusions in section 4 are still valid, which in line with the fact that nearly all firms in the sample report that they face some competition.

Finally, another concern is that the variables used to estimate the efficiency explanatory equation are influenced by the firms’ profit level. To address this issue, I re-estimate the profit frontier model for the years 2007-2015 and use the information on the firm-specific internal and external environment in 2005 to estimate the efficiency explanatory equation. The results from these empirical exercises do not change the relative importance of the firm-specific characteristics documented in section 4.

5.       Conclusion

As private firms play an important role in fostering local economic development, it is important to understand which factor is the most significant at boosting their performance. Yet, few studies have explored the relative importance of different variables on the firm-level efficiency, primarily because of the availability of data. Using a comprehensive dataset about firms in Vietnam, a transitional economy, this paper is among the first attempt at ranking the relative importance of various commonly-known efficiency determinants on private enterprises’ profitability.

The results suggest that Vietnamese private firms are operating at about two-thirds of their potential profitability. This result is in line with previous studies in other developing countries, therefore, Vietnam provides a good case study for other private firms in the developing world. In addition to estimating the efficiency gap, this paper also documents the marginal impact of various commonly-known determinants of efficiency on the firm-level profitability. Specifically, firm-specific characteristics are more important in shaping the profitability of a firm than characteristics of the external environment in which the firm operates. This implies that policies that encourage firms to improve their own internal strength are crucial to promote the firm-level efficiency. For example, improved access to the labor market, innovation incentives to upgrade the production process and labor training programs are found to be the most significant policies for the development of the private sector. In addition, the results also imply the importance of improving the external business and legal environment on the firm-level performance. Specifically, policy that fosters healthy competition and business partnerships is beneficial for the growth of private SMEs. Finally, improving the transparency of the legal system will reduce firms’ exposure to corruption, thereby increasing their profitability.

6.       References

[1]     AO. Ayandibu and J. Houghton. The Role of Small and Medium Scale Enterprise in Local Economic Development (LED). Journal of Business and Retail Management Research. 2017, 11(2).

[2]     CIEM, ILSSA, UCPH, & UNU-WIDER (2015). Vietnam Small and Medium Enterprise Survey.

[3]     A. Demenet, M. Razafindrakoto and F. Roubaud. Do informal businesses gain from registration and how? Panel data evidence from Vietnam. World Development. 2016, 84: 326-41.

[4]     M. J. Farrell. The measurement of productive efficiency. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (General). 1957, 120(3): 253–290.

[5]     General Statistics Office of Vietnam. Statistical Yearbook of Vietnam. Vietnam: Statistical Publishing House, 2015.

[6]     KB. Hailu and M. Tanaka. A “True” Random Effects Stochastic Frontier Analysis for Technical Efficiency and Heterogeneity: Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Ethiopia. Economic Modelling. 2015, 50: 179-92.

[7]     R. Kersten, J. Harms, K. Liket, and K. Maas. Small Firms, Large Impact? A Systematic Review of The SME Finance Literature. World Development. 2017, 97: 330-48.

[8]     J. Konings, and S. Vanormelingen. The Impact of Training on Productivity and Wages: Firm-Level Evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2015, 97(2): 485-97.

[9]     SC. Kumbhakar and H. Wang, AP. Horncastle. A Practitioner's Guide to Stochastic Frontier Analysis Using STATA. Cambridge University Press, 2015.

[10] J. Levinsohn, A. Petrin. Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables. The Review of Economic Studies. 2003, 70(2): 317-41.

[11] JH. Love and S. Roper. SME Innovation, Exporting and Growth: A Review of Existing Evidence. International Small Business Journal. 2015, 33(1): 28-48.

[12] G. Sandleris and ML. Wright. The Costs of Financial Crises: Resource Misallocation, Productivity, and Welfare in the 2001 Argentine Crisis. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics. 2014, 116(1): 87–127.

[13] C. Syverson. What Determines Productivity? Journal of Economic Literature. 2011, 49(2), 326–365.

[14] M. Wang M and MS. Wong. Effects of Foreign Direct Investment on Firm-Level Technical Efficiency: Stochastic Frontier Model Evidence from Chinese Manufacturing Firms. Atlantic Economic Journal. 2016, 44(3):335-61.

[15] Williams CC, Martinez-Perez A, Kedir A. Does Bribery Have a Negative Impact on Firm Performance? A Firm-Level Analysis across 132 Developing Countries. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research. 2016, 22(3): 398-415.